"15
Years of Privatization of Italian Cultural Heritage"
Working
Paper Author Roland Benedikter -
Stanford University Published 2011
Stanford
University Freeman Spogli Institute for International Studies The
Europe Center
Stanford
University Working Paper: Privatization of Italian Cultural Heritage
1996-2010
Part
I “The Real Dimension of the Process Is Not Visible to the Public
and the International Community”. The Three Problems Inbuilt into
the Privatization of Italian Cultural and Architectural Heritage
1996- 2010
An
Exclusive Introductory Talk between Salvatore Settis and Roland
Benedikter Stanford University
Scuola
Normale Superiore di Pisa, Italy January 13, 2011
First
transcript: Judith Hilber, MA Final version: Roland Benedikter
Roland
Benedikter: After fifteen years of privatization of Italian cultural
and architectural heritage between 1996 and 2010, we are still struggling
to get on our way towards a basic critical assessment of its achievements,
shortfalls, backgrounds, and perspectives. As far as the minimum
consensus in the international Social Sciences currently goes in
trying to put together a first overall picture, there were - and
are - at least three main problems inbuilt in this process. The
first two ones are mainly problems of methodology, i. e. of how
the process has been handled. Third, there are some crucial aspects
surrounding this process, which primarily regard its political and
economic contexts that seem to have heavily influenced it.
Salvatore
Settis:
Exactly.
Benedikter:
Due to the extraordinary complexity of the overall picture, let
me undertake one precautionary measure here right at the start.
Before talking about the privatization of cultural and architectural
heritage in Italy between 1996 and 2010 in the strict procedural
sense, we have to enlighten the very basic historical and legal
terms at the core of the current state of affairs which shape the
regulations and practices in effect. This is particularly important
for an Anglo-American audience which may otherwise struggle to understand
the full implications inbuilt in the process, and why it can be
regarded as problematic in the specific context in which it is taking
place.
Settis:
I agree. Here we already touch things at their core. Departing from
the terminological dimension, the methodological and contextual
dimensions become accessible more easily. So let us start with the
one basic term that constitutes the center of the whole issue.
Benedikter:
Which is ?
Settis:
The main traditional lead concept of cultural and architectural
heritage in Italy is demanio, or “public good”. The long history
of the concept of demanio in the Italian conservatory tradition
reaches back at least 2000 years, with more or less stable connotations
and enduring meanings and normative implications. It is totally
different from what Anglo-American readers are used to identifying
with the term “public property”. As a consequence, the whole idea
of “heritage alienation” or “privatization of 2 cultural heritage”
in Italy is different from what you would usually identify it with
in the Anglo-American world.
Benedikter:
In which sense ?
Settis:
Just to make a long story short, the idea of demanio goes back to
the Roman Empire. Since then, in whatever period of Italian history
up to our days, the idea of demanio has always been tied to the
core idea of public responsibility through public administration.
This was the case already long before the Italian unification in
1861, i.e. way before the birth of a national Italian state in the
modern sense. It was true for the city states - i.e. the comuni
- of the Middle Ages in Tuscany, for the kingdom of Naples in Southern
Italy and for the state of the Pope until 1870 in Rome. In all the
differing political and social environments throughout Italian history,
there has always been the idea of demanio, e.g. the idea of a “public
good” that constitutes the very core of what community and society
as such are.
Benedikter: “Public good” thus means more than “public property”,
namely sort of a symbolic and material embodiment of the communitarian
principle as such.
Settis:
Exactly. The understanding and self-interpretation of community
and society in Italy has always been quintessentially linked to
the very idea of common good, managed by some kind of public administration
or even state. The idea is that the public good has to be protected
by a public authority not primarily because it is something aesthetical
or of artistic quality in the strict sense, but much more because
it is a carrier of civil values, and a guarantor of social, of associated
life. It is the common bond that ties together the different social
experiences of different social classes like the rich and the educated,
and the rather humble parts of the populations, like the farmers
for example.
Benedikter:
This attitude obviously has nothing to do with socialism (it is
far older than any such concept), but rather with a lasting historical
and social awareness of the defining role of collective ownership
in shaping collective identity in Europe. It is not perceived as
being “against” private property, but as a truly complementary dimension
of equal importance, and this complementarity has always been and
still is decisive to the mindset of European societies. Seen from
an Anglo-American viewpoint, it might be just a remnant of traditional
(and maybe outdated) concepts of community. But in continental Europe
it is still very strongly felt as the indispensable second pillar
of how society as a whole is made up and functions. In contrast,
in the United States for example public property has never played
such a crucial role in defining society – on the contrary. In the
Anglo-American tradition, it is much more private than public property
that defines nation, state and society, like it is expressed in
the words: “My home is my castle” (UK) and “Privacy creates democracy”
(USA). There is no such fiercely protected balance between “private”
and “public” like in Europe – certainly with all pros and cons connected.
Settis:
Correct. So the concept of demanio in the strict Italian and European
sense does not exist in the USA (and most of the Anglo-Saxon world),
although there is of course the concept of public property. That’s
one point which should be underscored, because it is so crucial,
so critical to understand the difference between the continental
tradition of public property and what is true in other areas such
as the UK and even more so in the United States.
Benedikter:
Right.
Settis:
The second point to underscore here to understand the specifics
of the Italian privatization process is that within the demanio,
i.e. public good, not everything belongs to what is more precisely
called demanio culturale. Demanio culturale is a sub-concept of
demanio; and as such it is part of it, but not identical with it.
So within the public property of the Italian national state, which
in relation to the population and to the total of property is one
of the largest in Europe and probably in the world, there are many,
many objects - comprising buildings, military areas, but also large
plots of land, 3 mountains, islands and beaches, which terminologically
speaking are indeed part of the demanio, but not of the demanio
culturale. For instance, when somebody dies with no heirs and with
no testament, his or her property might be incorporated by the state.
It could be a flat, an apartment in a condominium built ten years
ago, which has clearly no cultural value and which clearly doesn’t
belong to the dimension of cultural property. In this case it becomes
part of public property, but certainly not of the demanio culturale.
Benedikter:
Precisely. I think it is very important to make this distinction
clear, because the enormous quantity of public property, of single
items currently belonging to the demanio of Italy derives precisely
from the fact that under the umbrella of the term “public property”
there are very different things that are summarized under it, but
that are not necessarily and not in any case part of the concept
of “public good”. All of them certainly belong to the state and
are thus public property, but most of them have no defining value
for the community, its historical collective memory and its socio-cultural
“founding myth”.
Settis:
Now it becomes obvious that when we talk about “privatization”,
we have to make some distinctions. It’s very different conceptually
if we talk about the privatization of let’s say a school built in
1965 which is no longer in a good state or a series of small “postmodern”
mainstream apartments of the 1980s on the one hand, or if we talk
on the other hand about privatizing the seat of the president of
the Italian Republic, the Palazzo del Quirinale, or important monuments
like the Colosseum or the Pantheon, which clearly belong to the
demanio culturale. What I want to point out is that there is a strong
terminological difference between what is called “privatization”
depending on the differentiation of demanio in demanio generale
and demanio culturale. And thus there must also be a strong
principal difference in enacting the respective processes. The distinction
between demanio generale and demanio culturale should be made very
clear right from the start; otherwise it looks like everything would
belong to demanio culturale. And I think one real failure, one of
the reasons for the failure of the attempts of selling or privatizing
a portion of public property or real estate belonging to the demanio
is precisely because this distinction has never been made as clearly
as it should have by the Italian governments from 1996 until today.
The lack of a sufficient distinction between demanio generale and
demanio culturale is the origin and the cause of most of the confusion
inherent in the process of privatization so far. It is at the very
roots of its enormous ambivalences and problems.
Benedikter:
Building upon these seminal terminological differentiations, let
us proceed now to the three problems inbuilt in the Italian privatization
process I mentioned initially. I propose we go point by point and
start with the first of the two methodological problems. One outstanding,
characteristic feature of the Italian privatization process is that
the Italian cultural and architectural heritage is being sold not
by one, but simultaneously by two ministries: the Ministry for Economy
which is leading the process, and the Ministry for Cultural Heritage
which has an auxiliary role to the extent that it can in theory
deny specific sellings by pointing out their historical and cultural
value. But rather to improve the efficiency, transparency and precision
of the process, this administrative double-dimensionality seems
on the contrary to have increased uncertainty, opacity and unreliability.
It seems to have also created a noticeable information gap, since
a lot of information is obviously continuously lost in the space
between the two authorities, as well as in inner administrative
and procedural conflicts between different departments about the
already administratively and politically highly disputed and fragmented
procedure of “heritage alienation”.
Settis:
Right.
Benedikter:
The second crucial, equally complex methodological problem institutionally
and structurally inbuilt in the current practice of privatization
is the partition of the selling process between the state and its
20 regions and other local bodies, like provinces, cities and municipalities.
Some assets are sold by the two state ministries, some others autonomously
by the regional and local authorities, without any explicit coordinated
methodology recognizable and without a clearly 4 identifiable oversight
institution that collects, integrates and distributes all data and
information of all the actors involved. That risks to cloud the
specifics of the process by making it very difficult, if not nearly
impossible to provide coordinated and up-to-date overall statistics.
It contributes to the dramatic shortage of statistical material
everybody who wants to research the issue as a whole in an empirical
manner immediately notices.
Settis:
This is indeed objectively the case. I guess not even the most expert
Italian analysts and practitioners themselves, including the national
and regional administrators, have sufficient data and statistics
at hand. The sad truth, as I can personally confirm after more than
2 years of service as President of the "Higher Council for
Cultural Heritage“ of the Italian Ministry
for Cultural Activities and Cultural Heritage, is that as at today,
due to the over-complicated ways in which the selling process is
handled, there is no satisfying, not even approximately sufficient
information available – for nobody, not even for the experts who
carry out the process.
Benedikter:
While this fact seems to be rather unusual, it has certainly been
brought to the attention of the governmental authorities many times
during the past 15 years. As it seems, not much has been done. Since
my last publication on the topic in 2004, I myself have repeatedly
and officially approached both ministries and several regional authorities
with the request of data, but none of them could give me any satisfying
statistics. What was even more surprising is that there was no specific
information about the privatization
of cultural and architectural heritage available at all,
not even by the Ministero dei beni culturali. All they could provide
me in the past 7 years was some general information about the intentions
and goals of the privatization process envisaged for the timeframe
2000-2010, but without any distinction, as you rightly mentioned,
between the privatization of demanio generale and demanio culturale.
Thus none of the available data, and I repeat: there are basically
no overall data, but only pieces of selected and scattered documentation
in different archives, can tell which of the sold or still to sell
properties are of cultural and architectural value, and which are
not.
Settis: Yes, and exactly this is the main problem.
Benedikter:
But again: Given that everybody can see this problem immediately
and that it has been pointed out so many times during the past 15
years, why is there still such a dramatic lack of statistical and
empirical material? Why do we not find any clear information, thus
being hindered to sketch any empirically based overall picture of
the privatization process ? Why are the ministries in Italy hesitating
to share any more meaningful information ? Is this incompetence,
or is there a method in it ? Is it on purpose ?
Settis:
You ask a question which everyone asks, and must ask, and which
we indeed have asked for many years. A proper answer to this question
can’t come from me, but must come from the respective public offices
- starting with the two ministries, the Ministry of Economy on which
the privatization of public property depends, and the Ministry of
Cultural Heritage, or beni culturali, which has a kind of advisory
and occasional veto status in the process.
Benedikter:
Right.
Settis:
This is a very sensitive issue which is being debated quite hotly
in Italy today, as you know. My impression is that the approach
not just of the current minister of economy Giulio Tremonti, but
of all the Italian ministers of economy throughout the history of
the last 15 years has been lacking clarity on what is the essential
distinction between demanio generale and demanio culturale. The
result is that whenever a sale of some demanio generale is announced
by the authorities, everybody is afraid, or a lot of people are
afraid that something of it could belong to the demanio culturale.
Therefore, there are always statements and polemical declarations
or interviews against it on the newspapers, which sadly in most
cases are very general and do not address the concrete contextual
circumstances, thus making them weak and imprecise, if not unfounded
right from the start.
Benedikter:
Which means ?
Settis:
My impression is that the lack of clear statistics and of clear
information, the idea of distributing all the information in very
small pieces that is totally impossible to put together for everybody,
including a serious researcher as you are, for whose efforts we
should be much grateful, I came to think that this is on purpose.
I came to think that this is precisely to avoid the level of clarity
and transparency that would be required. In order to make it clear
to the general public both in Italy and outside Italy to what extent
public property is being put on sale regarding the demanio culturale,
we would need basic statistical information. This has not been provided.
That is a fact, and it seems to be clear who is to blame on it in
the long run. It is 15 years now that we have been kept blind !
Benedikter:
Let us eventually come to the third - and final - problem cluster
inbuilt in the privatization process of Italian cultural and architectural
heritage: the political and economic contexts that seem to have
been strongly influencing it since it started. In many cases, the
privatization process seems to have been used as a playground for
political power games extraneous to the issue.
Settis:
Indeed, this is a third important dimension to consider. It is strongly
intertwined with the methodological problems though, since to a
large extent it factually co-created them. The political influence,
including political power games of all sorts between the left and
the right, but also within most of the parties present in the Italian
parliament, started right together with the implementation of the
laws that triggered the privatization process. So we have to start
with a short remembrance of what the political process in Italy
has produced as privatization laws since the mid 1990s. You gave
a brilliant overview on it in your excellent article on the issue
in the “International Journal of Heritage Studies” of 2004.
Benedikter:
It all started with the fall of the Berlin wall in 1989 and with
the collapse of the East-Westdichotomy in 1991. After years of fierce
debate over privatization issues influenced by the then prevailing
“neoliberal” mindset, in 2002 the (in)famous law on the Patrimonio
dello stato SPA was issued by the Italian parliament. It created
a semi-private enterprise of this name, to which all public properties
that were decided to be privatized should be transferred to by the
state, in order to be sold then according to the rules of the international
real estate markets.
Settis:
Yes, and this was in its core an attempt to induce the rules of
international private capitalism into the public sector. It was
clear though right from the start that this law would be very difficult
to implement, because there were too many polemical statements against
it, including a very influential one from the then Presidente della
Repubblica Carlo Azeglio Ciampi, and by many other opinion leaders
to whom, in 2002, my book “Italia S.P.A.” (i.e., Stock Company Italy)
gave a collective voice. In view of these difficulties, one of the
strategies applied to make the sale of public property nevertheless
possible on a broad scale was a diversion strategy. This strategy
led to political agreements between national, regional and other
local authorities (comuni) to transfer large parts of the demanio
dello stato into demanio regionale. The idea behind it was that
once public property of disputed cultural or historical value is
formally not any longer of national, but of regional ownership,
it should have in principle the same status of being inalienable,
but it becomes less controllable. It becomes less controllable because
now instead of having one owner (the Italian national state), you
have 21 authorities to deal with (given that one of the 20 regions
of Italy, Trentino-Alto Adige, is actually not one region but consists
of two autonomous provinces, and thus it is governed by two different
regional governments). Additionally, a lot of property was transferred
from the regions to the provinces that make them up, i.e. to even
smaller administrative units, and from the provinces to the single
cities and municipalities, or comuni. This has been made possible
because the demanio of public goods, according to the existing laws
still in effect, can in principle be demanio dello stato, demanio
della regione, demanio della provincia, or even demanio del comune.
Benedikter:
This kind of administrative dispersion seems not really a measure
to increase transparency and oversight.
Settis:
Not at all – on the contrary. After the transfer, the status of
cultural and architectural heritage theoretically remains the same;
but it becomes impossible for anybody to follow what the comune
di Verona is selling or the comune di Venezia or the comune di Palermo
all throughout Italy. Now this fragmentation, this segmentation
of public demanio makes it even more difficult to understand how
much has already been sold in the past, and what will be going on
where and to which extent in the future. It makes it virtually impossible
to take stock of the process, or to make any coordinated projections.
Benedikter:
Right. For the moment being, the last act of this drama has been
the introduction of the so-called federalismo demaniale (federalization
of public property) as a guiding principle for the whole of public
property in Italy by the Italian parliament on May 28, 2010 (decreto
legislativo 28 maggio 2010, no. 85). Proposed by the current fourth
government of Prime Minister Silvio Berlusconi and approved by his
conservative-right-wing majority in the two chambers of the parliament,
according to it a considerably more significant amount of public
goods belonging to the Italian stato will be transferred to the
single regions or other local bodies. Although
the current agreement seems to largely exclude properties of explicit
cultural value from the selling process, it is foreseen that this
is subject to renegotiation and further change.
Settis:
Exactly. And you must consider that the current agreement now includes,
for instance, the Dolomites, an ensemble of protected mountains
and natural parks in Northern Italy declared part of the world wide
natural heritage by UNESCO in June 2009. According to the potential
privatization of public property, the Dolomites were pre-emptively
put a prize upon by the Italian Ministry of Economy, which was published
in February 2011 at the official website of the Agenzia del demanio
della Repubblica Italiana (Official Agency for the Administration
of Public Property of the Italian Republic) at less than one and
a half million euros.
Benedikter:
That sounds unbelievable. It seems rather surreal to put a price
tag on a mountain chain that covers more than 120 square miles,
or even on parts of it like the Monte Cristallo mountain group officially
priced in its “inventory value” (valore inventariale) in the publication
of the Agenzia you mention.
Settis:
Indeed, who could believe that large part of the Dolomites could
be priced as “inventory”, and at less than one and a half million
euros! That doesn’t mean that they are actually for sale, but it
means that the administration wants to keep this option open. It
is a rather symbolic procedure that aims to point out that basically
all public property, including the very land and nature of Italy,
is in principle “alienable”.
Benedikter:
Yes. Rather than a concrete plan of transaction this seems to be
a public signal: an attempt to get the public used to the idea that
in principle, Italy has the option of selling everything, including
its own soil, in order to even out the national budget if needed.
Settis:
Right. Again, the point I’m trying to make is that such public signals
or symbolic price tags are accompanied by a more or less systematic
strategy of diversion. Any attempt of controlling and statistically
evaluating the entire process is made virtually impossible by the
dissolution of administrative responsibilities which has been accelerated
over the last couple of years. The dissolution of the demanio dello
stato and its segmentation into a huge number of actually hundreds
of demani culturali, demani regionali, demani provinciali and demani
comunali through the new federalismo demaniale makes the entire
process even less controllable than it used to be.
Benedikter:
In pursuing these policies, is there any significant difference
between the (past and present) centre-left and centre-right wing
parties (as they call themselves)? It surprisingly seems that this
is a policy of opacity that has been put into place by basically
all governing political parties between 1996 and 2010, including
the left and the right in similar ways. So an observer not familiar
with the domestic political background in Italy would wonder how
it is possible that such a crucial process like the privatization
of “the public good” can be carried out in such a non transparent
manner over fifteen years quite similarly by swiftly changing governments.
There seems to be only a small difference between the left and the
right concerning these privatization policies.
Settis:
Right. I think that the difference between the centre-left and the
centre-right governments since the 1990s has been more in terms
of quantity than in terms of quality. This has different reasons.
One of these reasons is positive to my mind, some others are negative.
The good reason is that the amount of public property of real estate
in public hands in Italy is objectively too large. It counts hundreds
of thousands of buildings and objects, and many thousands of unused
land areas. At the same time, Italy has a very large public debt;
actually one of the largest in the world, not just in relation to
the size of the GDP, but also in terms of pro capita. So something
had - and has - to be done, because it makes no sense that so much
property, including property which has no cultural value, is kept
in public hands and sometimes is not utilized at all over many decades
thus declining quickly, while Italy has such a large deficit in
terms of its national budget.
Benedikter:
Right. The stark imbalance between the amount of public property
the Italian national state holds and its means to keep it in an
acceptable shape is one good reason that lies behind the entire
process of privatization of the demanio. I think everybody in current
Italy would agree with that. So there is a comparatively broad public
consensus that the process of privatization is in principle legitimate,
and necessary.
Settis: And this basic consensus is shared by both the centre-left
and centre-right political parties alike, as it is reasonable in
my view. What I’m worried about is that within this reasoning, the
distinction between demanio generale and demanio culturale in a
stricter sense has never been made clear by any government. Not
even by the centre-left government from 1998 until 2001 under the
prime ministers Massimo D’Alema and Giuliano Amato, when the minister
of cultural heritage was Giovanna Melandri, who was probably one
of the most engaged ministers to protect the national cultural heritage,
and to keep it a “public good” in the strict sense of the term.
She made an attempt to distinguish the two levels, but in ways that
due to the very high level of complexity of the issue in the end
resulted to be far from being clear. Benedikter: In any case, we
can summarize that since the deficit of the Italian public budget
is so huge, all governments of centre-left and centre-right have
been consistent in their will to reduce it in some way, and therefore
indistinctively all of them have been willing to sell some public
property.
Settis:
Right. Nevertheless, a negative side aspect that should be taken
into consideration just in brackets here is that Italy has a very
large amount of people who don’t pay taxes, and they should. I think
that within Western Europe, Italy has a record in tax evasion. So
it is true that Italy needs more state income in order to reduce
the public debt, but I think that we should focus much more on a
good fiscal policy in making people pay their taxes, than in selling
the public good. Which is something the right definitely doesn’t
want to do, and the left does very timidly. When there was Tommaso
Padoa - Schioppa as minister of economy and finance from May 2006
until May 2008, he did something about it, and the amount of tax
evasion was slightly reduced. But immediately afterwards when Berlusconi
came back to the government, tax evasion increased again. So I believe
there has to be a more general rethinking of public policy not only
regarding the size of sellings in the framework of the privatization
process, but about the whole philosophy of making the public sphere
more functional.
Benedikter:
Let’s come to a conclusion now, and to an approximate outlook. You
have been in charge in many important public positions in the past
fifteen years that have directly or indirectly been connected to
the process of conservation of Italian cultural and architectural
heritage, as well as to its privatization. You have often criticized
the practices of the privatization process, and you’ve published
about it critically. What is your personal résumé, your overall
judgement about the process over the past 15 years? What went well,
and what went wrong? And where are the perspectives ?
Settis:
I’ve never been in a directly deciding position. I’ve been working
mainly at the university, which has nothing to do with this process.
But I have also been president of the Consiglio superiore dei beni
culturali, a sort of a supreme council of cultural heritage of the
Republic of Italy for two consecutive periods from 2006 to 2009.
Unfortunately, this council has no direct decision power. It is
only a consulting body which can be consulted by the minister and
the state, but then the minister can do whatever he or she wants.
So I have never been in a position to really influence the decision-making
process. That’s the reason why I decided to try to make clear some
aspects of what is going on by writing in newspapers which I had
almost never done before. But in the last ten years or so I started
writing more frequently on a daily basis just to make it clear to
the public what is at stake with the privatization process. My personal
idea is that I’m in favour of selling parts of the public property
whenever it doesn’t have any historical or cultural value. That
is the case for a large amount of real estate currently in public
hands. On the other hand I think that in relation to what is the
civic and legal culture of Italy, it would be against the whole
tradition from pre-unification Italy to the present to abolish public
property of culturally significant land and real estate. The tradition
of public ownership should be preserved, with more public money
invested in its conservation. I believe this money can come not
least from a better commercial use of the public buildings which
in fact can be put into practical use. I don’t want a general mystification
of indistinctively all public property in Italy. But in general,
I believe public buildings can be put into use. It can be given
to different non-profit institutions, for instance, that actually
do need buildings and venues where to carry out their activities.
But in order to make any progress here, we need a clear distinction
between what is demanio culturale and what is public property with
no cultural value, i.e. demanio generale.
Benedikter:
So what is the state of things here? Have there been new, current
approaches made in this direction ?
Settis:
The state of things is that to implement such a basic distinction
will not be simple, given the large amount of public property and
its scattered ownership on different administrative levels. But
in your previous publications on the issue, you made a very intelligent
and important remark about the fact that the Ministry for Cultural
Heritage has never completed a census of all the buildings in public
hands of cultural value. While such a list has been completed in
one way or another for the demanio generale by the Ministry for
Economy, the fact that it has not been compiled in agreement with
the Ministry of Cultural Heritage diminishes its value. We need
such a national list of all public goods of cultural value, and
we need it as soon as possible, because its a shame that a modern
nation like Italy, one of the seven most industrialized nations
with the sixth-highest government budget in the world, does not
have it at hand yet with all the electronic and computer options
and the new communication technologies available.
Benedikter:
Right.
Settis:
Additionally, we have to consider that Italy still has the relatively
largest amount of people of all Europe countries employed in the
public sector of cultural heritage in the broad sense, currently
about 20,000 people. The so-called soprintendenze (public monument
protection services) are one of the largest working forces dedicated
to cultural and historical heritage in the world.
Benedikter:
Without any doubt, even if the total numbers have been slightly
decreasing over the past years.
Settis:
Now if you take these two aspects together: the still missing complete
census of buildings of cultural value, and the unusually large number
of public employees in this sector, it is easy to see what has to
be done as a concrete next step. The national authorities should
make use of a much larger part of the employees working in the broad
field of demanio in order to achieve a more or less complete inventory,
even if it probably may remain utopia to have a complete inventory
of really everything. But if you achieve 95%, the census might not
be complete, but it would be quite a lot. This inventory should
be the first thing to be accomplished now; it should be given top
strategic priority. The second step should be to see then how many
of the existing buildings of cultural value are actually used for
public purposes, i.e. for what in the Italian legal tradition has
been called bonum comune or publica utilitas, which has been the
core purpose of demanio from the Roman law up to the present. And
the third step could be to distinguish those buildings that will
be needed by the public sphere also in the future, from those that
are in public hands but could be sold, because not needed or of
only minor cultural and historical value. So we need first of all
a comprehensive list, and then a much more filigree and systematic
differentiation within this list.
Benedikter:
Another proposal - a fourth step if you like - could be to identify
potential reutilizations of existing, non-used buildings of cultural
value. There is a huge number of public institutions like schools,
universities, libraries, public offices, city administrations, provincial
authorities and so forth that are notoriously short of space and
are constantly looking for old buildings they could reutilize. Why
should they not get culturally important old buildings currently
left empty, and thus often gravely neglected ?
Settis:
Yes. I think the theme of reusing old buildings for new purposes
is a very important part of the overall solution pattern. Putting
them for sale in order to transform them into privately owned and
run hotels or apartments should in any case not be the only solution
considered. Again, to make reasoned decisions here, we first of
all need a full list of all buildings available, and second a clear
distinction between demanio generale and demanio culturale regarding
every single building.
Benedikter:
But who could make such a distinction? Would you need a special
national commission composed of scientists, specialists or public
administrators? Or who else could do such a delicate and far-reaching
differentiation on a systematic, professional basis ?
Settis:
The professional 20,000 employees in the soprintendenze who are
already there. They have in their large majority been trained as
art and architecture historians. They have been employed exactly
for purposes of evaluation, research and differentiation like the
one needed, but have been totally left out of the process so far.
The reason why the soprintendenze are not functioning as well as
they could in contributing to the differentiation of the privatization
process is that they are left out of this process precisely because
they have the competencies to say: “This particular building is
too precious to be sold”. That’s why the Ministry of Economy doesn’t
want to hear their opinion. Second, over the last fifteen years
both the centre-left and centre-right governments have stopped hiring
new professionals in the sector, so there has been no turnover.
The result is that the average age of people working in the sopraintendenze
now in 2011 is over 55, which means some of them are not always
up to date with the current state of things and the new technologies
available. In order to make use of the soprintendenze to accomplish
the goals we have sketched above as top priorities, the Italian
system of soprintendenze has to be revived.
Benedikter:
To conclude, what is your personal balance sheet of the process?
Where do you see the biggest mistakes that have been made during
the past fifteen years, and where are the biggest successes of the
privatization process that you would identify ?
Settis:
The two main mistakes are first the lack of a clear distinction
between what of the demanio belongs to the greater cultural good,
and what doesn’t. The second mistake consists in the fact that 10
the Italian state does indeed have a body of highly qualified public
officers who are paid, not very much, but who are paid in order
to give their advice and their opinion about how to handle the cultural
and architectural heritage, but are normally not consulted when
the Ministry of Economy decides to sell something. I think these
are the two biggest mistakes. It is sincerely difficult to see any
particularly outstanding successes of the privatization process
so far. Besides that, as we said, in some instances in principle
it may be legitimate.
Benedikter:
Has Italy in your opinion lost some important cultural buildings
or cultural heritage due to these mistakes? In other words: Have
these mistakes produced concrete consequences as at yet ?
Settis:
Given the lack of statistical and empirical information, it is very
difficult to respond to this question. So far, the real quantitative
and qualitative dimension of the privatization process is not visible
– neither to the public in Italy, nor to the international community.
This can be interpreted in two different ways. If you want to be
optimistic, you can say that maybe a lot of properties have been
sold, but not truly important ones, given that we are not aware
of such sales. On the other hand, if you want to be pessimistic,
you can say that a lot of properties may have been sold, but a sort
of cloud has been created that shadows the process, so that it has
become virtually impossible to understand how much of what exactly
has been sold. Certainly in your remarkable article of 2004 you
mentioned some concrete cases of “alienation”, and there are certainly
many more in the meantime. But I think we are not in the position
to issue an empirically founded judgement so far. And that is both
a matter of concern and a reason of hope.
Benedikter:
Looking at the present situation, which of these two feelings should
prevail: concern or hope? Do you see any movements toward improvement
on the political side? Or is the privatization process likely to
be going, as many fear, in the wrong direction, continuing with
an opacity that creates a development which the public basically
cannot judge? From my - and other colleagues’ - point of view this
would be the most dangerous variant of all, because that would mean
that there is a process that nobody is really in control of and
which is basically going on without overall coordination.
Settis:
Unfortunately, my answer is that concern must prevail, because what
you are rightly describing is the present reality. It is, realistically
speaking, the present outlook. I can see no political improvement.
Given the constraints and problems added by the recent financial
and economic crisis that goes far beyond Italy, but that hit Italy
particularly badly, the temptation of selling more and more and
of continuing to cloud the process by making it even less transparent
will be continuing to be there. Nevertheless, I do hope that sooner
or later - and I certainly hope rather sooner than later - at some
point somebody, whether it’s the current government or another centre-left
government, will recognize that we need improvements in how the
process is carried out and handled. I don’t care about what government
it will be. I just know that we need to improve things, and first
of all to make the privatization process more transparent. Today
it is certainly still not transparent at all.
Benedikter:
Where do you imagine could the future of this process be in ten
years from now? It is highly probable that the political and administrative
culture of the Berlusconi era, which since his first office as prime
minister in 1994 lasted altogether for more than 17 years, may come
to an end soon - be it because of new elections, or because Berlusconi
is approaching retirement age. What is the future in your view?
Will new governments, will new leaders change things? And: Will
Italy continue to have a (maybe necessarily) ambivalent stance towards
its over-rich and over-abundant cultural and architectural heritage
- or was the privatization process of the past 15 years just a temporary
passage in its history that will soon be only a distant memory ?
Settis:
Predicting what is going to happen in the Italian political situation
is as you know very difficult, and that’s not something that I could
engage in. I’d like to say something else. I’d say what worries
me most is that even if Berlusconi resigned tomorrow and even if
there were elections in a couple of months, even if a centre-left
government came in his place, I’m not at all sure whether the privatization
11 process would become more transparent. Maybe even the contrary
would be the case. So what is the most worrying part of this story
to me is the fact that no political party in current Italy, neither
Berlusconi’s parties nor the leftist coalition, have a clear awareness
of the true importance of the privatization process, and of how
to address it properly. Whatever the political destiny of this country
is going to be, I feel what is needed now is, more than ever, a
rise in public awareness. That is what I hope for.
Benedikter:
As you wrote in a more detailed manner in your last book on Paesaggio,
costituzione e cemento (2010), you are advocating in favour of forming
public opinion through newspapers and independent citizens associations
that might end up by influencing the political parties sooner or
later. Settis: Right. The only thing I am truly optimistic about
is that there are now in Italy a couple of thousand small civil
society associations and some larger associations of citizens detached
from the established political parties that advocate in favour of
landscape protection, better conservation of public patrimony, better
conservation of cultural heritage and so forth. And I think this
is already increasing public awareness in this country, which I
think is what we badly need. Benedikter: Let’s hope that this talk
and the related essay may contribute to such a rise of awareness,
and to a positive development.
Settis:
That’s what I hope too. Thank you very much.
The
Authors
Salvatore
Settis, Prof. Dott., has been Director of the Getty Research
Institute in Los Angeles (1994- 1999) and of the Scuola Normale
Superiore di Pisa (1999-2011). He was also a founding member of
the European Research Council, and is a Member of the International
Committee for the Protection of the „Leaning Tower of Pisa“ and
of the Scientific Council of the „Encyclopedia Italiana“, editor-in-chief
of the publication series “Mirabilia Italiae”. From 2006 until 2009
he has been President of the „Higher Council for Cultural Heritage“
of the Italian Ministry for Cultural Activities and Cultural Heritage
Rome. He currently serves as professor of Art History at the Museo
del Prado in Madrid, and chairs the Scientific Council of the Musée
du Louvre in Paris. E-mail: settis@sns.it
Roland
Benedikter, Prof. Dott. lett. Dr. phil. Dr. phil. Dr. rer. pol.,
serves as European Foundation Research Professor of Sociology in
residence at the Orfalea Center for Global and International Studies
of the University of California at Santa Barbara, and as Research
Affiliate / Visiting Scholar 2009-13 at the Europe Center, Stanford
University, USA. E-mail: rben@stanford.edu or rbenedikter@orfaleacenter@ucsb.edu
|